囫囵吞枣是什么意思| 小米什么时候成熟| 什么样的女人性欲强| 蜻蜓点水是什么生肖| 豆蔻是什么| darker是什么意思| 6月25是什么星座| 经常拉肚子挂什么科| 什么是鸡眼| 脑梗吃什么药好| 手术后喝什么鱼汤最好| 广肚是什么| 黔驴技穷是什么意思| 哈尔滨机场叫什么名字| 绛紫色是什么颜色| 脚发热是什么原因| 11月27日是什么星座| 智商120是什么水平| 花椒吃多了对身体有什么影响| 改户口需要什么手续| 什么叫缘分| 乳腺增生是什么意思| 过敏性紫癜千万不能用什么药| 弯脚杆是什么意思| 喉咙有白点是什么原因| 血糖高忌吃什么| 脚脱皮什么原因| 多云是什么意思| 眼睛视物模糊是什么原因| 乙肝阳性是什么意思| 骨折恢复吃什么好| 甲鱼跟什么炖最补| 小肠与什么相表里| 一个火一个羽一个白念什么| 露出什么意思| 命理是什么意思| 蚊子喜欢什么味道| 托帕石是什么宝石| 梦见着火是什么意思| 耳鸣是什么意思| 氯雷他定不能和什么药一起吃| 蝾螈是什么| 拉肚子可以吃什么| 平安扣适合什么人戴| 朊病毒是什么| 皮肤一碰就破是什么病| 怀孕周期是从什么时候开始算的| 74年出生属什么生肖| 洗头什么时间洗最好| 没主见是什么意思| 痔疮挂什么科| 梦见掉头发是什么意思| 凤仙花什么时候开花| 虎什么熊什么| 衣服的英文是什么| 一笑泯恩仇什么意思| 张学良为什么叫小六子| 劳烦是什么意思| 轻浮的女人是什么意思| 造化是什么意思| tspot检查阳性能说明什么| 什么是植物神经| 梦见冬瓜是什么意思| 前列腺炎什么症状| 内膜增厚是什么原因| 尿胆红素高是什么原因| 男生下巴长痘痘是什么原因| 经常性偏头疼是什么原因| 澄字五行属什么| 渗透压低是什么意思| 梦见自己被抢劫了预示什么| 监督的近义词是什么| 褒义词和贬义词是什么意思| 中国最好的大学是什么大学| dha中文叫什么| 铠是什么意思| 阿司匹林是什么| 拔牙后吃什么恢复快| 九二年属什么| 站点是什么意思| 霸王别姬是什么生肖| 周深为什么是女声| 私房菜是什么意思| 脚气去医院挂什么科| 什么是流程| 生存是什么意思| 眼睛充血用什么眼药水最好| 10月13号是什么星座| 长期低血糖对人体有什么危害| 小肠与什么相表里| 大便黑色是什么原因| 脾胃虚弱吃什么食物| 宁夏有什么特产| 角化棘皮瘤是什么病| 喝蒲公英根有什么好处| cbs是什么意思| 欧多桑是什么意思| 醋泡黑豆有什么功效| cll是什么意思| 口干舌燥喝水也不解渴是什么原因| 轻度脂肪肝什么意思| alan什么意思| 生肖羊和什么生肖相冲| 噬血细胞综合征是什么病| n是什么牌子的鞋| 为什么胸部会胀痛| 眼睛发粘是什么原因| 五味是什么| 皮肤为什么会痒| 翔字五行属什么| 隆胸有什么危害和后遗症吗| 尿道下裂是什么意思| 0101是什么意思| 10月10日是什么星座| 甲状腺结节看什么科室最好| 什么是幂| 地势是什么意思| 2.13是什么星座| 酵素是什么| 龋读什么| 为什么打哈欠会传染| 香芋紫是什么颜色| 阿斯伯格综合征是什么| 脾大是什么原因引起的| 高抬贵手是什么意思| 属兔本命佛是什么佛| 水疱疹什么药最快能治好| 农历3月3是什么节日| 2030年属什么生肖| 什么睡姿有助于丰胸| 生肖本命带红花是什么生肖| 什么含钾最多| 鲍鱼吃什么| 麦克白夫人什么意思| 输卵管囊肿是什么原因引起的| lu是什么单位| 喘不上气挂什么科| 补钙吃什么| 脂肪液化是什么意思| 头颅mri是什么检查| 咳嗽吐黄痰是什么原因| 黄昏是什么时辰| 海参不适合什么人吃| 梦见打老鼠是什么征兆| 五十肩是什么意思| 早上口干苦是什么原因| 曹植是什么生肖| imp是什么意思| 独一味是什么药| 十月二十二是什么星座| 零点是什么意思| 商字五行属什么| 79年属什么| 女性睾酮低意味着什么| 肾宝片是什么| 妄想什么意思| 看脑血管挂什么科| tc什么意思| 6月20号是什么星座| 梦见蝴蝶是什么意思| 增大摩擦力的方法有什么| 孩子出汗多是什么原因| 教师节是什么时候| 以免是什么意思| 牙龈发炎用什么药| 眼睛飞蚊症用什么眼药水| 唐僧肉是什么意思| 肾阳虚吃什么药| 啃手指甲是什么毛病| 天天喝奶茶有什么危害| 双星座是什么意思| 食人鱼长什么样| 减肥吃什么米| 牙痛吃什么药最管用| 时间观念是什么意思| 大便感觉拉不干净什么原因| 什么锤百炼| 记忆力下降是什么原因引起的| 酸碱度偏高是什么意思| 女人出汗多是什么原因| 晚上睡觉遗精是什么原因| 舌苔很厚很白什么原因| 肚脐眼大代表什么| 苦口婆心是什么意思| 人放屁多是什么原因| 平头哥是什么意思| 神经性头疼吃什么药好| 黑皮肤适合穿什么颜色的衣服| 宝宝为什么吐奶| 一个口一个且念什么字| 毛新宇什么级别| 射精快吃什么药| 胎监什么时候开始做| cto是什么意思| 夏天脚冷是什么原因| 恩师是什么意思| 手镯断了有什么预兆| 痛经看什么科| 洋葱有什么好处| 胃息肉是什么原因引起的| 心眼多是什么意思| 8月15号什么星座| pet一ct是一种什么检查| 派石项链有什么功效| 什么情况下需要做肠镜检查| 沧海遗珠是什么意思| 乐松是什么药| 衣服五行属什么| 点痣用什么方法最好| 向日葵的花语是什么| 脚趾头麻木是什么原因| 本命佛是什么意思| 650是什么意思| 什么解酒快| 2008年是属什么| 小孩子为什么会得抽动症| 康妇炎胶囊主治什么| ochirly是什么牌子| 什么叫同房| 牙科属于什么科| 浮夸是什么意思| 投诉医院打什么电话| 排卵期后面是什么期| 小葫芦项链是什么牌子| 二十二岁属什么| 嘴巴里长水泡是什么原因| 肝脏在什么位置| 五四运动是什么| 快餐是什么意思| 小孩睡觉出很多汗是什么原因| 为什么总长火疖子| 爆缸是什么意思| 灰指甲用什么药效果好| 口琴买什么牌子好| 妈妈是什么意思呢| 均一性红细胞什么意思| 狗肚子有虫子吃什么药| 眼睛有红血丝是什么原因| eland是什么牌子| 成人男性尿床是什么原因造成的| 还替身是什么意思| 寸头是什么意思| 七月十二是什么星座| 情人眼里出西施是什么意思| 痔疮什么东西不能吃| degaia是什么牌子| lin是什么意思| 夕阳西下是什么意思| 口苦是什么原因| 萎靡不振是什么意思| 提溜是什么意思| 湖北古代叫什么| 乳头内陷是什么原因| 一直吐口水是什么原因| 生粉是什么| 1962年属虎的是什么命| refill是什么意思| 吃什么丰胸效果最好最快| pangchi是什么牌子的手表| 外痔疮是什么样子图片| 女性更年期吃什么药| 翩翩起舞是什么意思| 反复发烧是什么原因引起的| 腰疼吃什么药效果好| 百度Jump to content

上曼月乐环后要注意什么

From Wikipedia, the free encyclopedia
百度 但队员们似乎有约在先,他们一致表示,深圳红钻俱乐部必须偿清他们的薪酬,绝不接受分期偿付,否则就拒绝参加明晚与北京八喜的中甲比赛。

Zero-sum game is a mathematical representation in game theory and economic theory of a situation that involves two competing entities, where the result is an advantage for one side and an equivalent loss for the other.[1] In other words, player one's gain is equivalent to player two's loss, with the result that the net improvement in benefit of the game is zero.[2]

If the total gains of the participants are added up, and the total losses are subtracted, they will sum to zero. Thus, cutting a cake, where taking a more significant piece reduces the amount of cake available for others as much as it increases the amount available for that taker, is a zero-sum game if all participants value each unit of cake equally. Other examples of zero-sum games in daily life include games like poker, chess, sport and bridge where one person gains and another person loses, which results in a zero-net benefit for every player.[3] In the markets and financial instruments, futures contracts and options are zero-sum games as well.[4]

In contrast, non-zero-sum describes a situation in which the interacting parties' aggregate gains and losses can be less than or more than zero. A zero-sum game is also called a strictly competitive game, while non-zero-sum games can be either competitive or non-competitive. Zero-sum games are most often solved with the minimax theorem which is closely related to linear programming duality,[5] or with Nash equilibrium. Prisoner's Dilemma is a classic non-zero-sum game.[6]

Definition

[edit]
Choice 1 Choice 2
Choice 1 ?A, A B, ?B
Choice 2 C, ?C ?D, D
Generic zero-sum game
Option 1 Option 2
Option 1 2, ?2 ?2, 2
Option 2 ?2, 2 2, ?2
Another example of the classic zero-sum game

The zero-sum property (if one gains, another loses) means that any result of a zero-sum situation is Pareto optimal. Generally, any game where all strategies are Pareto optimal is called a conflict game.[7][8]

Zero-sum games are a specific example of constant sum games where the sum of each outcome is always zero.[9] Such games are distributive, not integrative; the pie cannot be enlarged by good negotiation.

In situation where one decision maker's gain (or loss) does not necessarily result in the other decision makers' loss (or gain), they are referred to as non-zero-sum.[10] Thus, a country with an excess of bananas trading with another country for their excess of apples, where both benefit from the transaction, is in a non-zero-sum situation. Other non-zero-sum games are games in which the sum of gains and losses by the players is sometimes more or less than what they began with.

The idea of Pareto optimal payoff in a zero-sum game gives rise to a generalized relative selfish rationality standard, the punishing-the-opponent standard, where both players always seek to minimize the opponent's payoff at a favourable cost to themselves rather than prefer more over less. The punishing-the-opponent standard can be used in both zero-sum games (e.g. warfare game, chess) and non-zero-sum games (e.g. pooling selection games).[11] The player in the game has a simple enough desire to maximise the profit for them, and the opponent wishes to minimise it.[12]

Solution

[edit]

For two-player finite zero-sum games, if the players are allowed to play a mixed strategy, the game always has at least one equilibrium solution. The different game theoretic solution concepts of Nash equilibrium, minimax, and maximin all give the same solution. Notice that this is not true for pure strategy.

Example

[edit]
A zero-sum game (Two person)
Blue
Red
A B C
1
?30
30
10
?10
?20
20
2
10
?10
?20
20
20
?20

A game's payoff matrix is a convenient representation. Consider these situations as an example, the two-player zero-sum game pictured at right or above.

The order of play proceeds as follows: The first player (red) chooses in secret one of the two actions 1 or 2; the second player (blue), unaware of the first player's choice, chooses in secret one of the three actions A, B or C. Then, the choices are revealed and each player's points total is affected according to the payoff for those choices.

Example: Red chooses action 2 and Blue chooses action B. When the payoff is allocated, Red gains 20 points and Blue loses 20 points.

In this example game, both players know the payoff matrix and attempt to maximize the number of their points. Red could reason as follows: "With action 2, I could lose up to 20 points and can win only 20, and with action 1 I can lose only 10 but can win up to 30, so action 1 looks a lot better." With similar reasoning, Blue would choose action C. If both players take these actions, Red will win 20 points. If Blue anticipates Red's reasoning and choice of action 1, Blue may choose action B, so as to win 10 points. If Red, in turn, anticipates this trick and goes for action 2, this wins Red 20 points.

émile Borel and John von Neumann had the fundamental insight that probability provides a way out of this conundrum. Instead of deciding on a definite action to take, the two players assign probabilities to their respective actions, and then use a random device which, according to these probabilities, chooses an action for them. Each player computes the probabilities so as to minimize the maximum expected point-loss independent of the opponent's strategy. This leads to a linear programming problem with the optimal strategies for each player. This minimax method can compute probably optimal strategies for all two-player zero-sum games.

For the example given above, it turns out that Red should choose action 1 with probability ?4/7? and action 2 with probability ?3/7?, and Blue should assign the probabilities 0, ?4/7?, and ?3/7? to the three actions A, B, and C. Red will then win ?20/7? points on average per game.

Solving

[edit]

The Nash equilibrium for a two-player, zero-sum game can be found by solving a linear programming problem. Suppose a zero-sum game has a payoff matrix M where element Mi,j is the payoff obtained when the minimizing player chooses pure strategy i and the maximizing player chooses pure strategy j (i.e. the player trying to minimize the payoff chooses the row and the player trying to maximize the payoff chooses the column). Assume every element of M is positive. The game will have at least one Nash equilibrium. The Nash equilibrium can be found (Raghavan 1994, p. 740) by solving the following linear program to find a vector u:

Minimize:

Subject to the constraints:

u ≥ 0
M?u ≥ 1.

The first constraint says each element of the u vector must be nonnegative, and the second constraint says each element of the M?u vector must be at least 1. For the resulting u vector, the inverse of the sum of its elements is the value of the game. Multiplying u by that value gives a probability vector, giving the probability that the maximizing player will choose each possible pure strategy.

If the game matrix does not have all positive elements, add a constant to every element that is large enough to make them all positive. That will increase the value of the game by that constant, and will not affect the equilibrium mixed strategies for the equilibrium.

The equilibrium mixed strategy for the minimizing player can be found by solving the dual of the given linear program. Alternatively, it can be found by using the above procedure to solve a modified payoff matrix which is the transpose and negation of M (adding a constant so it is positive), then solving the resulting game.

If all the solutions to the linear program are found, they will constitute all the Nash equilibria for the game. Conversely, any linear program can be converted into a two-player, zero-sum game by using a change of variables that puts it in the form of the above equations and thus such games are equivalent to linear programs, in general.[13]

Universal solution

[edit]

If avoiding a zero-sum game is an action choice with some probability for players, avoiding is always an equilibrium strategy for at least one player at a zero-sum game. For any two players zero-sum game where a zero-zero draw is impossible or non-credible after the play is started, such as poker, there is no Nash equilibrium strategy other than avoiding the play. Even if there is a credible zero-zero draw after a zero-sum game is started, it is not better than the avoiding strategy. In this sense, it's interesting to find reward-as-you-go in optimal choice computation shall prevail over all two players zero-sum games concerning starting the game or not.[14]

The most common or simple example from the subfield of social psychology is the concept of "social traps". In some cases pursuing individual personal interest can enhance the collective well-being of the group, but in other situations, all parties pursuing personal interest results in mutually destructive behaviour.

Copeland's review notes that an n-player non-zero-sum game can be converted into an (n+1)-player zero-sum game, where the n+1st player, denoted the fictitious player, receives the negative of the sum of the gains of the other n-players (the global gain / loss).[15]

Zero-sum three-person games

[edit]
Zero-sum three-person game
Zero-sum three-person game

It is clear that there are manifold relationships between players in a zero-sum three-person game, in a zero-sum two-person game, anything one player wins is necessarily lost by the other and vice versa; therefore, there is always an absolute antagonism of interests, and that is similar in the three-person game.[16] A particular move of a player in a zero-sum three-person game would be assumed to be clearly beneficial to him and may disbenefits to both other players, or benefits to one and disbenefits to the other opponent.[16] Particularly, parallelism of interests between two players makes a cooperation desirable; it may happen that a player has a choice among various policies: Get into a parallelism interest with another player by adjusting his conduct, or the opposite; that he can choose with which of other two players he prefers to build such parallelism, and to what extent.[16] The picture on the left shows that a typical example of a zero-sum three-person game. If Player 1 chooses to defence, but Player 2 & 3 chooses to offence, both of them will gain one point. At the same time, Player 1 will lose two-point because points are taken away by other players, and it is evident that Player 2 & 3 has parallelism of interests.

Real life example

[edit]

Economic benefits of low-cost airlines in saturated markets - net benefits or a zero-sum game [17]

[edit]

Studies show that the entry of low-cost airlines into the Hong Kong market brought in $671 million in revenue and resulted in an outflow of $294 million.

Therefore, the replacement effect should be considered when introducing a new model, which will lead to economic leakage and injection. Thus introducing new models requires caution. For example, if the number of new airlines departing from and arriving at the airport is the same, the economic contribution to the host city may be a zero-sum game. Because for Hong Kong, the consumption of overseas tourists in Hong Kong is income, while the consumption of Hong Kong residents in opposite cities is outflow. In addition, the introduction of new airlines can also have a negative impact on existing airlines.

Consequently, when a new aviation model is introduced, feasibility tests need to be carried out in all aspects, taking into account the economic inflow and outflow and displacement effects caused by the model.

Zero-sum games in financial markets

[edit]

Derivatives trading may be considered a zero-sum game, as each dollar gained by one party in a transaction must be lost by the other, hence yielding a net transfer of wealth of zero.[18]

An options contract - whereby a buyer purchases a derivative contract which provides them with the right to buy an underlying asset from a seller at a specified strike price before a specified expiration date – is an example of a zero-sum game. A futures contract – whereby a buyer purchases a derivative contract to buy an underlying asset from the seller for a specified price on a specified date – is also an example of a zero-sum game.[19] This is because the fundamental principle of these contracts is that they are agreements between two parties, and any gain made by one party must be matched by a loss sustained by the other.

If the price of the underlying asset increases before the expiration date the buyer may exercise/ close the options/ futures contract. The buyers gain and corresponding sellers loss will be the difference between the strike price and value of the underlying asset at that time. Hence, the net transfer of wealth is zero.

Swaps, which involve the exchange of cash flows from two different financial instruments, are also considered a zero-sum game.[20] Consider a standard interest rate swap whereby Firm A pays a fixed rate and receives a floating rate; correspondingly Firm B pays a floating rate and receives a fixed rate. If rates increase, then Firm A will gain, and Firm B will lose by the rate differential (floating rate – fixed rate). If rates decrease, then Firm A will lose, and Firm B will gain by the rate differential (fixed rate – floating rate).

Whilst derivatives trading may be considered a zero-sum game, it is important to remember that this is not an absolute truth. The financial markets are complex and multifaceted, with a range of participants engaging in a variety of activities. While some trades may result in a simple transfer of wealth from one party to another, the market as a whole is not purely competitive, and many transactions serve important economic functions.

The stock market is an excellent example of a positive-sum game, often erroneously labelled as a zero-sum game. This is a zero-sum fallacy: the perception that one trader in the stock market may only increase the value of their holdings if another trader decreases their holdings.[21]

The primary goal of the stock market is to match buyers and sellers, but the prevailing price is the one which equilibrates supply and demand. Stock prices generally move according to changes in future expectations, such as acquisition announcements, upside earnings surprises, or improved guidance.[22]

For instance, if Company C announces a deal to acquire Company D, and investors believe that the acquisition will result in synergies and hence increased profitability for Company C, there will be an increased demand for Company C stock. In this scenario, all existing holders of Company C stock will enjoy gains without incurring any corresponding measurable losses to other players.

Furthermore, in the long run, the stock market is a positive-sum game. As economic growth occurs, demand increases, output increases, companies grow, and company valuations increase, leading to value creation and wealth addition in the market.

Complexity

[edit]

It has been theorized by Robert Wright in his book Nonzero: The Logic of Human Destiny, that society becomes increasingly non-zero-sum as it becomes more complex, specialized, and interdependent.

Extensions

[edit]

In 1944, John von Neumann and Oskar Morgenstern proved that any non-zero-sum game for n players is equivalent to a zero-sum game with n + 1 players; the (n + 1)th player representing the negative of the total profit among the first n players.[23]

Misunderstandings

[edit]

Zero-sum games and particularly their solutions are commonly misunderstood by critics of game theory, usually with respect to the independence and rationality of the players, as well as to the interpretation of utility functions[further explanation needed]. Furthermore, the word "game" does not imply the model is valid only for recreational games.[5]

Politics is sometimes called zero sum[24][25][26] because in common usage the idea of a stalemate is perceived to be "zero sum"; politics and macroeconomics are not zero-sum games, however, because they do not constitute conserved systems.[27][28] Applying zero-sum game logic to scenarios that are not zero-sum in nature may lead to incorrect conclusions. Zero-sum games are based on the notion that one person's win will result in the other person's loss, so naturally there is competition between the two. There are scenarios, however, where that is not the case. For instance, in some cases both sides cooperating and working together could result in both sides benefitting more than they otherwise would have. By applying zero-sum logic, we in turn create an unnecessary, and potentially harmful, sense of scarcity and hostility.[29] Therefore, it is critical to make sure that zero-sum applications fit the given context.

Zero-sum thinking

[edit]

In psychology, zero-sum thinking refers to the perception that a given situation is like a zero-sum game, where one person's gain is equal to another person's loss.

See also

[edit]

References

[edit]
  1. ^ Cambridge business English dictionary. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. 2011. ISBN 978-0-521-12250-4. OCLC 741548935.
  2. ^ Blakely, Sara. "Zero-Sum Game Meaning: Examples of Zero-Sum Games". Master Class. Master Class. Retrieved 2025-08-06.
  3. ^ Von Neumann, John; Oskar Morgenstern (2007). Theory of games and economic behavior (60th anniversary ed.). Princeton: Princeton University Press. ISBN 978-1-4008-2946-0. OCLC 830323721.
  4. ^ Kenton, Will. "Zero-Sum Game". Investopedia. Retrieved 2025-08-06.
  5. ^ a b Ken Binmore (2007). Playing for real: a text on game theory. Oxford University Press US. ISBN 978-0-19-530057-4., chapters 1 & 7
  6. ^ Chiong, Raymond; Jankovic, Lubo (2008). "Learning game strategy design through iterated Prisoner's Dilemma". International Journal of Computer Applications in Technology. 32 (3): 216. doi:10.1504/ijcat.2008.020957. ISSN 0952-8091.
  7. ^ Bowles, Samuel (2004). Microeconomics: Behavior, Institutions, and Evolution. Princeton University Press. pp. 33–36. ISBN 0-691-09163-3.
  8. ^ "Two-Person Zero-Sum Games: Basic Concepts". Neos Guide. Neos Guide. Archived from the original on 2025-08-06. Retrieved 2025-08-06.
  9. ^ Washburn, Alan (2014). Two-Person Zero-Sum Games. International Series in Operations Research & Management Science. Vol. 201. Boston, MA: Springer US. doi:10.1007/978-1-4614-9050-0. ISBN 978-1-4614-9049-4.
  10. ^ "Non Zero Sum Game". Monash Business School. Retrieved 2025-08-06.
  11. ^ Wenliang Wang (2015). Pooling Game Theory and Public Pension Plan. ISBN 978-1507658246. Chapter 1 and Chapter 4.
  12. ^ Von Neumann, John; Oskar Morgenstern (2007). Theory of games and economic behavior (60th anniversary ed.). Princeton: Princeton University Press. p. 98. ISBN 978-1-4008-2946-0. OCLC 830323721.
  13. ^ Ilan Adler (2012) The equivalence of linear programs and zero-sum games. Springer
  14. ^ Wenliang Wang (2015). Pooling Game Theory and Public Pension Plan. ISBN 978-1507658246. Chapter 4.
  15. ^ Arthur H. Copeland (July 1945) Book review, Theory of games and economic behavior. By John von Neumann and Oskar Morgenstern (1944). Review published in the Bulletin of the American Mathematical Society 51(7) pp 498–504 (July 1945)
  16. ^ a b c Von Neumann, John; Oskar Morgenstern (2007). Theory of games and economic behavior (60th anniversary ed.). Princeton: Princeton University Press. pp. 220–223. ISBN 978-1-4008-2946-0. OCLC 830323721.
  17. ^ Pratt, Stephen; Schucker, Markus (March 2018). "Economic impact of low-cost carrier in a saturated transport market: Net benefits or zero-sum game?". Tourism Economics: The Business and Finance of Tourism and Recreation. 25 (2): 149–170.
  18. ^ Levitt, Steven D. (February 2004). "Why are Gambling Markets Organized so Differently from Financial Markets?". The Economic Journal. 114 (10): 223–246. doi:10.1111/j.1468-0297.2004.00207.x. S2CID 2289856 – via RePEc.
  19. ^ "Options vs. Futures: What's the Difference?". Investopedia. Retrieved 2025-08-06.
  20. ^ Turnbull, Stuart M. (1987). "Swaps: A Zero Sum Game?". Financial Management. 16 (1): 15–21. doi:10.2307/3665544. ISSN 0046-3892. JSTOR 3665544.
  21. ^ Engle, Eric (September 2008). "The Stock Market as a Game: An Agent Based Approach to Trading in Stocks". Quantitative Finance Papers – via RePEc.
  22. ^ Olson, Erika S. (2025-08-06). Zero-Sum Game: The Rise of the World's Largest Derivatives Exchange. John Wiley & Sons. ISBN 978-0-470-62420-3.
  23. ^ Theory of Games and Economic Behavior. Princeton University Press (1953). June 25, 2005. ISBN 9780691130613. Retrieved 2025-08-06.
  24. ^ Rubin, Jennifer (2025-08-06). "The flaw in zero sum politics". The Washington Post. Retrieved 2025-08-06.
  25. ^ "Lexington: Zero-sum politics". The Economist. 2025-08-06. Retrieved 2025-08-06.
  26. ^ "Zero-sum game | Define Zero-sum game at". Dictionary.com. Retrieved 2025-08-06.
  27. ^ Grofman, Bernard (January 1982). "A dynamic model of protocoalition formation in ideological n-space". Behavioral Science. 27 (1). Wiley: 77–90. doi:10.1002/bs.3830270108. ProQuest 1301274043. See p. 88: "politics is not a zero-sum game".
  28. ^ Adler, Paul S. (October 1982). "A Review Essay: The productivity puzzle: numbers alone won't solve it" (PDF). Monthly Labor Review. 105 (10): 15–21. JSTOR 41841699. See p. 20: "growth in capitalist economies is not a zero-sum game".
  29. ^ "What does it mean to see the world as a zero-sum competition?". Gates Cambridge.

Further reading

[edit]
  • Misstating the Concept of Zero-Sum Games within the Context of Professional Sports Trading Strategies, series Pardon the Interruption (2025-08-06) ESPN, created by Tony Kornheiser and Michael Wilbon, performance by Bill Simmons
  • Handbook of Game Theory – volume 2, chapter Zero-sum two-person games, (1994) Elsevier Amsterdam, by Raghavan, T. E. S., Edited by Aumann and Hart, pp. 735–759, ISBN 0-444-89427-6
  • Power: Its Forms, Bases and Uses (1997) Transaction Publishers, by Dennis Wrong, ISBN 978-1-56000-822-4
[edit]
cas是什么意思 疱疹用什么药好得快 茄子什么人不能吃 镇团委书记是什么级别 补肾吃什么药最好
女生为什么会喷水 马黛茶什么味道 喝铁观音茶有什么好处 物欲横流是什么意思 麻薯是什么
千斤拔泡酒有什么功效 柠檬酸是什么添加剂 排卵期是在什么时候 吕布的坐骑是什么 既寿永昌什么意思
孩子白细胞高是什么原因 一什么杯子 正山小种属于什么茶 1955年属羊的是什么命 低钠盐是什么意思
人流后吃什么恢复快hcv7jop6ns7r.cn 赢字五行属什么hcv7jop5ns5r.cn 白羊和什么星座最配hcv7jop5ns1r.cn 吃东西恶心想吐是什么原因hcv7jop9ns3r.cn 鳌虾吃什么hcv7jop6ns3r.cn
隆胸有什么危害和后遗症吗hcv9jop5ns7r.cn 九地是什么中药inbungee.com 企鹅是什么动物hcv8jop4ns7r.cn 生物包括什么hcv8jop5ns6r.cn 黄芪可以和什么一起泡水喝xscnpatent.com
糠是什么hcv9jop4ns2r.cn 小孩流鼻血是什么原因hcv7jop5ns5r.cn 孕妇吃火龙果有什么好处hcv7jop7ns0r.cn 保险属于什么行业hcv9jop2ns2r.cn 梦见纸钱是什么预兆hcv7jop6ns0r.cn
1030是什么星座hcv9jop4ns6r.cn 75年的兔是什么命hcv8jop5ns5r.cn 胸部挂什么科hcv7jop9ns8r.cn 长期便秘吃什么药效果最好hcv9jop2ns7r.cn 917是什么意思hcv8jop5ns8r.cn
百度